Financial Transaction Tax Essay, Research Paper
The soaring volume of international finance and increased interdependence in
recent decades has increased concerns about volatility and threats of a financial crisis.
This has led many to investigate and analyze the origins, transmission, effects and policies
aimed to impede financial instability. This paper argues that financial liberalization and
speculation are the most reflective explanations for instability in financial markets and that
financial instability is likely to be transmitted globally with far reaching implications on real
sector performance. I conclude the paper with the argument that a global transaction tax
would be the most effective policy to curb financial instability and that other proposed
policies, such as target zones and the creation of a supranational institution, are either
unfeasible or unattainable.
INSTABILITY IN FINANCIAL MARKETS
In this section I examine four interpretations of how financial instability arises.
The first interpretation deals with speculation and the subsequent ?bandwagoning? in
financial markets. The second is a political interpretation dealing with the declining status
of a hegemonic anchor of the financial system. The question of whether regulation causes
or mitigates financial instability is raised by the third interpretation; while the fourth view
deals with the ?trigger point? phenomena.
To fully comprehend these interpretations we must first understand and
differentiate between a ?currency? and ?contagion? crisis. A currency crisis refers to a
situation is which a loss of confidence in a country?s currency provokes capital flight.
Conversely, a contagion crisis refers to a loss of confidence in the assets denominated in a
particular currency and the subsequent global transmission of this shock.
One of the more paramount readings of financial instability pertains to speculation.
Speculation is exhibited in a situation where a government monetary or fiscal policy (or
action) leads investors to believe that the currency of that particular nation will either
appreciate or depreciate in terms relative to those of other countries. Closely associated
with these speculative attacks is what is coined the ?bandwagon? effect. Say for
example, that a country?s central bank decides to undertake an expansionary monetary
policy. A neoclassical interpretation tells us that this will lower the domestic interest
rates, thus lowering the rate of return in the foreign exchange market and bringing about a
currency depreciation. As investors foresee this happening they will likely pull out before
the perceived depreciation. ?Efforts to get out would accelerate the loss of reserves,
provoking an earlier collapse, speculators would therefore try to get out still earlier, and
so on? (Krugman, 1991:93). This ?herding? or ?bandwagon? effect naturally cause wild
swings in exchange rates and volatility in markets.
Another argument for the evolution of financial market instability is closely related
to hegemonic stability theory. This political explanation predicts a circumstance (i.e. a
decline of a hegemon?s status) in which a loss of confidence in a particular countries
currency may lead to capital flight away from that currency. This flight in turn not only
depreciates the currency of the former hegemon but more importantly undermines its role
as the international financial anchor and is said to ultimately lead to instability.
The trigger point phenomena may also be used as an instrument to explain financial
instability. Similar to the speculative cycles described above, this refers to a situation
where a group of investors commits to buy or sell a currency when that currency reaches a
certain price level. If that particular currency were to rise or fall to that specified level,
whether by real or speculative reasons, the precommited investors buy or sell that
currency or assets. This results in a cascade effect that, like speculative cycles, increases
or decreases the value of the currency to remarkably higher or lower levels.
Country after country has deregulated its financial markets and institutions. The
neoclassical interpretation asserts that regulation is thought to create incentives for risk
taking and hence instability. It is said to bring about what are called ?moral hazards.?
Proponents of deregulation argue that when people are insured, they are more apt to take
greater risks with their investments in financial markets. The riskier the investment
activity, the more volatile the markets tend to be.
A closer look suggests that perhaps only two of these explanations are valid when
thinking about the origins of financial instability. The trigger point explanation seems to
be a misreading of the origins of instability. It is unlikely that a large number of investors
would have the incentive or operational ability in order to simultaneously coordinate the
buying or selling of a currency or assets denominated in that currency. If even there is
such unlikely coordination, the ?existence of even a very large group of investors with
trigger points need not create a crisis if other investors know they are there? (Krugman,
1991:96).
The theory of hegemonic stability also overlooks a number of factors that can
provide useful insights in explaining the emergence of financial instability. Historical
precedence supports this assertion. For instance, Britains role as international economic
manager was very minor in the stability experienced under the gold standard. The success
of the standard can be attributed to endogenous factors such as the self adjusting market
mechanism and the informal discipline maintained by its rules. The destabilization of the
gold standard can be attributed to the extreme domestic economic and financial pressures
brought on nation states by World War I, and not solely on the industrial and economic
demise of Britain.
A valid explanation for the origins of financial instability are the speculative attacks
brought on by investors. Although similar in function to trigger points, these speculative
cycles cannot be mitigated simply by pure recognition. Rather than acting on the value of
the currency itself, speculators act on occurrences or policies that will alter the value of
the currency. Instability arises from the fact that these speculative cycles induce capital
flight and therefore a change in the value of that particular currency, whether or not the
decisions of these investors are based on market ?fundamentals.? Futures, options, swaps
and other financial instruments ?have given investors and speculators an unheard of
capacity to leverage financial markets. The greater the leverage, the greater the
instability? (McCallum, 1995:12).
If we examine the deregulatory process closely, it becomes clear that there is a
perverse relationship between deregulation and financial stability. Say for example,
investors suffer from a profit squeeze. This causes the investors to lobby politicians for
deregulation. The resulting wave of deregulation fosters instability and wide swings in
exchange rates which in turn cause loan defaults and subsequent banking crisis. The
resulting financial instability thus begs calls regulation, likely placing the investors in the
original position with an unsolved problem. We can see that the dialectic of the regulatory
process undermines anticipated stability and will eventually lead to financial instability and
collapse. In this environment, there arises calls for new forms of financial regulation.
These policies and proposals are of critical importance and will therefore be discussed
later in the paper.
THE TRANSMISSION AND EFFECTS OF FINANCIAL INSTABILITY
There are three contending albeit interrelated views on how financial instability
may be transmitted globally. These include equity markets, multiplier effects and
monetary reverberations.
Say for example, a movement of stock prices generates a recession in one country.
This is turn leads to a reduce in imports from abroad. The lower aggregate demand for
foreign imports will generate a contraction in other country?s output markets. The
resulting contraction in the foreign countries will then induce a contraction in the
originating country. As seen, the multiplier effect begins to take place that in turn leads
to a global recession.
If an asset crash leads to a monetary crises, the money crisis could be transmitted
worldwide. The Mundell-Flemming model assumes that under a fixed exchange rate
system, such as that under the gold standard, a worldwide monetary contraction will result
from a contraction in any one particular country because ?a monetary contraction in one
country, which raises interest rates in that country, must be matched by an equal rise in
rates elsewhere? (Krugman, 1991:103). However, under a flexible exchange rate system,
such as the one in operation today, the model predicts that monetary shocks will be
transmitted perversely, that is, a monetary contraction in one country will produce
expansion elsewhere. Herring and Litan (1995) advance this argument by concluding that
the transmission of crisis creates a ?systemic risk.? This view states that continuous
losses in financial markets has adverse effects on the real economy because ?significant
losses can occur if there is a significant disruption in the payments system or the
mechanism through which transactions for goods, services, and assets are cleared?
(Herring and Litan, 1995:51) .
While it may be accepted that financial crises can be transmitted globally, there is
debate on its ramifications on the real sector of the economy. Krugman (1991:97) states
that a currency depreciation ?will produce an improvement in competitiveness that will
increase net exports and thus have an expansionary effect on the domestic economy.? He
also asserts that policy responses may help to curb real sectors effects. When currencies
depreciate, government officials and central bankers raise interest rates to discourage
capital flight. The recessionary effects of tight monetary and fiscal policies, it is argued,
dilute the inflationary repercussions of the currency crisis. Citing historical evidence of the
US stock market crash, Kapstein (1996:6) goes so far as to say that the real economy is
?shockproof? from transmission of financial instability and even in the face of financial
crisis ?continues to function normally.?
The assumption that swings in financial markets do not influence real sector
performance is inattentive to many factors. Advocates of this view use what is percieved
as relatively small repercussions felt worldwide after the US stock market crash in 1929
where ?in general the slump was mild? (Krugman 1991:91). The empirical data of the
slump underscores this argument. Between December 1929 and December 1932, for
example, Germany experienced a 30.% percent stock market decline, France 38.5 percent
and Canada 37.5% (Kindleberger, 1973). If we keep in mind that the percentage swing in
the US stock during that same period was 37.3 percent, we see that the slump was only
slightly ?milder? but by no means ?mild.? The real sector ramifications were just as
remarkable. Germany saw a 58 percent decline in industrial production, France 74 percent
and Canada 68 percent, all comparably higher declines than in the United States (Yeager,
1976).
It is obvious that financial crises do have global spillover effects and consequences
on real sector performance. However, recognition of these adverse effects does not solve
the problem. In the next section I present contending policies and proposals designed to
curb international financial instability and its repugnant ramifications.
CONTENDING VIEWS AND POLICY PROPOSALS
Three main policies have been introduced to curb international financial instability.
A global transaction tax, which is a tax on short term financial investments, a target zone
approach, where nations exchange rates would be allowed to fluctuate within a specific
band and a supranational or regional institution aimed at coordinating global financial
reform.
Proposed by economists and Nobel Laureate James Tobin in 1978, a global
transaction tax (STT) would act to ?throw some sand in the well greased wheels of the
global financial markets.? The STT is predicted to slow the short term financial
excursions into other currencies, yet at the same time it would have a lighter impact on
trade and long-term investments with higher percentage yields. Speculators, now carrying
the burden of a tax woul therefore have less ?leverage? with which to exploit exchange
volatility while long-term investment would be encouraged. Another benefit of the tax is
that it would reduce wasted financial resources and increase government revenues.
While proponents of the STT say the policy will reduce wasted financial resources,
others argue that there would be an adjustment problem because of the fact that ?goods
and the price of labor moved in response to international price signals much more
sluggishly than fluid funds, and prices in goods and labor markets moved more sluggishly
than prices of financial assets.?(McCallum, 1995:16) Others attack the view that excess
volatility would be eliminated because ?deciding whether volatility is excessive is
complicated by difficulty of determining the fundamental value of a security? (Hakkio,
1994:22). Opponents of the tax argue that it could be avoided by product substitution and
regulatory arbitrage and that the government revenue created would be overestimated
because ?the tax base would decline as security prices and the volume of trading decline?
(Hakkio 1994: 26).
Advocates of the ?efficient market hypothesis? argue that if financial markets are
allowed to freely operate, there will be a revaluation of asset values that will produce the
most accurate price signals on which to base long-term resource allocations. They say that
a STT would be detrimental to less developed countries so reliant on short term
investment.
Another highly noted policy aimed at curbing international financial instability is
the adoption of a targeted exchange rate system. A sort of ?hybrid? regime, target zones
allows currencies to fluctuate within predetermined and set bands, thus allowing a ?float?
but at the same time keeping a ?fix.? Since ?the main sources of conflict have been the
unpredictability of exchange rates? (Frenkel, 1990:318) a target zone approach would in
theory alleviate this unpredictability, while keeping the appealing attributes of a floating
system. Seen to be the optimal answer for coordinated exchange rate stabilization, ?target
zones would involve the determination of an international consensus regarding an
appropriate and globally feasible range around which currency values could fluctuate?
(Grabel, 1993:77).
The adoption of a target zone system would not be universally beneficial.
Naturally, the size, status and sector of the economy play an important role in its
desirability. Government officials and central bankers will likely oppose the adoption of a
targeted exchange rate due to the fact that it would hurt their ability to change the value of
their currency in the face of high capital mobility. With a targeted exchange rate, it is
argued that there is limited room for fluctuation which infringes on the effectiveness of
domestic policies. On the other hand, the fixity of the target zone would in theory stabilize
purchasing power of wage earners in both developed and less developed.
The overriding problem of the adoption of a target zone regime is that there is no
clear way in which target zones could be calculated. If they were to be calculated what
would be the ramifications if a country was to fluctuate out of the specific bands? Would
the target zones be global or regional? If global, how could the less developed countries
be able to stay in the same bands as the developed countries? If a target zone was adopted,
what is to say the maldistribution of wealth would not remain idle? There seems to be
little, if any, evidence that a fixed, stabilized exchange rate leads to higher or lower interest
rates. If the value of a currency is not able to adapt to high tendencies of capital mobility,
then it is only rational to say that the developed countries would continue to sap the
wealth of less developed countries.
The last major policy aimed at quelling financial instability is the creation of a
supranational institution aimed at coordinating financial reform and adopting a system of
?regulatory supervision.? Processing along the lines of a Bretton Woods architecture, this